Case before Court threatens historical view of Constitution

David J. Porter

There is a widely held view that

Congress has virtually unlimited

power to legislate, especially concerning

economic matters.

Consider, for example, the passage

of the controversial Patient Protection

and Affordable Care Act two

years ago. While Congress’ power

to regulate the economy is not completely

unbounded, it is very farreaching

indeed. However, it was

not always so.

Under the Articles of Confederation,

Congress was powerless

to address conflicting commercial

regulations imposed by the several

states. To remedy that flaw, the enumerated

powers given to Congress

under the Constitution included the

authority “[t]o regulate Commerce

… among the several States.”

At the time the Constitution

was ratified, “commerce” referred

to trade—buying and selling products—

but it did not include all economic

activity, such as manufacturing,

agriculture, and labor. In the

ratification debates, there was little

deliberation over the Commerce

power because it was understood

to be an insignificant threat to local

or non-commercial affairs. James

Madison emphasized that point in

Federalist No. 45.

Early Congresses rarely invoked

the Commerce power. The

Supreme Court’s first opportunity to

determine its scope did not arise until

Gibbons v. Ogden (1824). In that

case, the Court held that Congress

may regulate interstate commerce,

but not commerce that doesn’t extend

to or affect other states.

Over the next century, the Court

reiterated that Congress’ Commerce

power did not include regulation of

production in anticipation of trade.

In these decisions, the Court emphasized

the distinction between commerce

and other types of economic

activity that are not commerce:

“Without agriculture, manufacturing,

mining, etc., commerce could

not exist, but this fact does not suffice

to subject them to the control

of Congress” (Newberry v. United

States, 1921).

A slight shift occurred in 1914,

when the Court held that where interstate

and intrastate aspects of

commerce are so intermingled, the

Constitution permits regulation of

interstate commerce even if that

results in incidental regulation of

purely intrastate commerce. But in

general, the Court’s view of Congress’

Commerce power remained

unchanged. In 1935, the Court held

that Congress may not regulate intrastate

sales of poultry, and as late as

1936, the Court invalidated a federal

law regulating labor because “the relation

of employer and employee is a

local relation.”

The Court’s century-old Commerce

Clause jurisprudence ultimately

bowed to far-reaching New Deal

laws. In NLRB v. Jones & Laughlin

Steel Corp. (1937), the Court upheld

the National Labor Relations Act

against a Commerce Clause challenge,

holding that Congress may

regulate intrastate production if it

has a “close and substantial relation

to interstate commerce.” And in

United States v. Darby (1941), the

Court declared that “[t]he power of

Congress over interstate commerce

is not confined to the regulation of

commerce among the states.”

Wickard v. Filburn (1942) is

generally considered the most expansive

Commerce Clause decision

to date. In that case, the Court

held that Congress could regulate a

farmer’s production and consumption

of homegrown wheat because

even though his activity was local,

was not commerce, and did not substantially

or directly affect interstate

commerce, it could, in combination

with others’ similar conduct, affect

interstate commerce.

In 1964 and 1971, the Supreme

Court rejected Commerce Clause

challenges to the application of civil

rights laws to motels and restaurants,

and to a federal criminal law

prohibiting local instances of loan

sharking. In these cases, the Court

dismissed arguments that: the regulated

activity was not commercial,

Congress was legislating against

moral wrongs, the activity was purely

local, and the economic effect of

the regulated activity was so small

as to be trivial.

In United States v. Lopez

(1995) and United States v. Morrison

(2000), the Supreme Court resisted

further expansion, a reminder

that even after the New Deal cases,

Congress’ Commerce power still has

outer limits. Because the federal laws

in Lopez and Morrison (prohibiting

possession of a gun near a school

and gender-motivated violence, respectively)

regulated local activity

having no effect on interstate commerce,

they were really exercises

of the general police power that belongs

exclusively to the states.

In the case now pending before

the Supreme Court on the Patient

Protection and Affordable Care Act,

the issue is whether Congress has the

power to compel non-participants

into the health insurance market, so

that they can then be regulated. It’s

a novel question, and no precedent

governs the Court’s decision. During

its oral argument, the federal government

asserted that every person

is an “actuarial reality” whose current

existence and eventual mortality

creates a statistically measurable

insurance risk.

By that theory, everyone is inescapably

a “participant” in the health

insurance market and therefore subject

to federal regulation. Such metaphysical

abstraction threatens not

merely to further stretch, but finally

to break the Framers’ structural design

that for 225 years has preserved

individual liberty and served as a

check on unlimited federal power.

— David J. Porter is an attorney

with Buchanan Ingersoll &

Rooney PC and a trustee of Grove

City College. The opinions expressed

by the author are his own.

Total
0
Share